Government investments and entrepreneurship
How can governments attract entrepreneurs and their businesses? The view that new business creation grows with the optimal level of government investment remains appealing to policymakers. In contrast with this active approach, we build a model where governments may adopt a passive approach to stimulating business creation. The insights from this model suggest new business creation depends positively on factors beyond government investments—attracting high-skilled migrants to the region and lower property prices, taxes, and fines on firms in the informal sector. These findings suggest whether entrepreneurs generate business creation in the region does not only depend on government investments. It also depends on location and skilled migration. Our model also provides methodological implications—the relationship between government investments and new business creation is endogenously determined, so unless adjustments are made, econometric estimates will be biased and inconsistent. We conclude with policy and managerial implications.
Plain English Summary
Governments can attract entrepreneurs and their businesses by offering incentives such as lower property prices, taxes, and fines on firms in the informal sector, as well as by encouraging skilled migration to the region. Thus, a policy implication is that the government can create a favorable environment for business creation as opposed to solely relying on government investments.
This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.
Access this article
Subscribe and save
Springer+ Basic
€32.70 /Month
- Get 10 units per month
- Download Article/Chapter or eBook
- 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
- Cancel anytime
Buy Now
Price includes VAT (France)
Instant access to the full article PDF.
Rent this article via DeepDyve
Similar content being viewed by others
Necessity or opportunity? Government size, tax policy, corruption, and implications for entrepreneurship
Article Open access 22 June 2021
Economic Development Incentives: Fostering Productive or Unproductive Entrepreneurship?
Chapter © 2021
Entrepreneurship policy and economic growth: Solution or delusion? Evidence from a state initiative
Article 21 June 2016
Data Availability
Data sharing is not applicable to this article as no new data were created or analyzed in this study.
Notes
Good Jobs First. (2022). Subsidy tracker. https://www.goodjobsfirst.org/subsidy-tracker
Greenstone and Moretti, 2003 studied the location of million-dollar business investments announced in the 1982–1993 period and provided an economic analysis of the value the local region of attracting large firms by weighing the benefits of employment and property value gains against the costs of incentive packages.
There are many different conceptualizations of entrepreneurs. Parker (2018) provides an excellent summary. We follow the advice of Welter et al. (2017) and refrain from adopting a narrow conceptualization of entrepreneurship.
See Packard and Bylund (2018) for criticism on the focus of this type of entrepreneurship.
Although we discuss government infrastructure investments, government investments can be quite broad. For example, according to Lerner (2010), Singapore implemented specific government policies such as: “The provision of public funds for venture investors seeking to locate in the city-state; Subsidies for firms in targeted technologies; Encouragement of potential entrepreneurs and mentoring for fledgling ventures; Subsidies for leading biotechnology researchers to move their laboratories to Singapore; Awards for failed entrepreneurs (with a desire to encourage risk-taking).”.
Although Bennett (2019b) excludes projects in the power, communication, and railroad sectors from private infrastructure investments, there are historical examples of private companies investing in these sectors. For example, James J. Hill built the Great Northern Railway from St. Paul to Seattle with no US government aid (Folsom, 1991).
This is in line with Thurik and Wennekers (2004) and Acs et al. (2016), which support government policy that targets skills supply through education, knowledge transfer, worker mobility, and the ability to start new firms.
An example of the type of infrastructure investments that we have in mind is a government investment in rural high-speed broadband (Cumming and Johan 2010), which is quite different than some other types of investment, like neighborhood beautification, in terms of how it affects entrepreneurship. Because the focus here is on job creation and destruction, we ignore the effects of government policy on low growth entrepreneurship, which deserves to be studied in a framework where its contributions to society are accounted appropriately, as advocated by Welter et al. (2017).
The Q in the model is a parameter that represents the spatial restrictions in the regional economy due to distance, negative agglomeration externalities, and/or regulations. The Q is assumed exogenous, being determined by regional idiosyncrasies like topography and land use regulations, which are typically disconnected from the government levels or entities that provide business incentives.
We assume decreasing returns in the public-good investment technology, such that x > 1, as in Acemoglu (2005).
The reverse is also likely true—business creation tends to attract more workers and immigrants. However, in our model, M is exogenously given, so the only causality possible in our model is from immigration to business creation. We thank one anonymous reviewer for pointing this out.
Bandyopadhyay and Pinto (2017) and Ogura (2018) find similar results in regard to the effect of immigration and informality on production.
Even if infrastructure investments do not affect business creation directly, they might have an indirect effect through property prices, taxes, and immigration. As such, a possible extension of the model is to integrate G into these functions. However, this exercise would make exogenous variables like property prices, taxes, and immigration endogenous, so we miss their important impact in the model and in the policy prescriptions. Moreover, this extension changes the model entirely, yielding a different analysis and results. Thus, we leave this extension for future research.
References
- Abdel-Rahman, H. M. (1988). Product differentiation, monopolistic competition and city size. Regional Science and Urban Economics,18, 69–86. https://doi.org/10.1016/0166-0462(88)90006-3ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Acemoglu, D. (2005). Politics and economics in weak and strong states. Journal of Monetary Economics, Political Economy and Macroeconomics,52, 1199–1226. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2005.05.001ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Ács, Z. J., Autio, E., & Szerb, L. (2014). National systems of entrepreneurship: Measurement issues and policy implications. Research Policy,43, 476–494. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2013.08.016ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Acs, Z. J., & Mueller, P. (2008). Employment effects of business dynamics: Mice, gazelles and elephants. Small Business Economics,30, 85–100. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-007-9052-3ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Acs, Z., & Szerb, L. (2007). Entrepreneurship, economic growth and public policy. Small Business Economics,28, 109–122. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-006-9012-3ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Acs, Z., Åstebro, T., Audretsch, D., & Robinson, D. T. (2016). Public policy to promote entrepreneurship: A call to arms. Small Business Economics,47, 35–51. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-016-9712-2ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Acs, Z. (2006). How is entrepreneurship good for economic growth? innovations 1, 97–107. https://doi.org/10.1162/itgg.2006.1.1.97
- Andersson, P., & Wadensjö, E. (2007). Do the unemployed become successful entrepreneurs? International Journal of Manpower,28, 604–626. https://doi.org/10.1108/01437720710830070ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Aparicio, S., Audretsch, D., & Urbano, D. (2021). Why is export-oriented entrepreneurship more prevalent in some countries than others? Contextual antecedents and economic consequences. Journal of World Business,56, 101177. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jwb.2020.101177ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Arauzo-Carod, J.-M., & Viladecans-Marsal, E. (2009). Industrial location at the intra-metropolitan level: The role of agglomeration economies. Regional Studies,43, 545–558. https://doi.org/10.1080/00343400701874172ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Audretsch, D. B., Keilbach, M. C., & Lehmann, E. E. (2006). Entrepreneurship and economic growth. Oxford University Press. BookGoogle Scholar
- Audretsch, D. B., Heger, D., & Veith, T. (2015). Infrastructure and entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics,44, 219–230. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-014-9600-6ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Audretsch, D. (2003). Entrepreneurship policy and the strategic management of places, in: Hart, D.M. (Ed.), The emergence of entrepreneurship policy: Governance, start-ups, and growth in the U.S. Knowledge Economy. UK: Cambridge University Press.
- Autio, E., & Rannikko, H. (2016). Retaining winners: Can policy boost high-growth entrepreneurship? Research Policy,45, 42–55. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2015.06.002ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Bandyopadhyay, S., & Pinto, S. M. (2017). Unauthorized immigration and fiscal competition. European Economic Review,92, 283–305. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2016.12.010ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Barrios, S., Görg, H., & Strobl, E. (2006). Multinationals’ location choice, agglomeration economies, and public incentives. International Regional Science Review,29, 81–107. https://doi.org/10.1177/0160017605281516ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Bennett, D. L. (2019). Infrastructure investments and entrepreneurial dynamism in the US. Journal of Business Venturing,34, 105907. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusvent.2018.10.005ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Bennett, D. L. (2019). Local economic freedom and creative destruction in America. Small Business Economics. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-019-00222-0ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Bennett, D. L. (2021). Local institutional heterogeneity & firm dynamism: Decomposing the metropolitan economic freedom index. Small Business Economics,57, 493–511. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-020-00322-2ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Bjørnskov, C., & Foss, N. J. (2016). Institutions, entrepreneurship, and economic growth: What do we know and what do we still need to know? The Academy of Management Perspectives,30, 292–315. https://doi.org/10.5465/amp.2015.0135ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Block, J. H., Fisch, C. O., & van Praag, M. (2018). Quantity and quality of jobs by entrepreneurial firms. Oxford Review of Economic Policy,34, 565–583. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxrep/gry016ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Bosma, N., Hill, S., Ionescu-Somers, A., Kelley, D., Levie, J., & Tarnawa, A., (2020). Global entrepreneurship monitor 2019/2020 global report. Global Entrepreneurship Research Association, London Business School, 5–7. UK.
- Boudreaux, C., & Nikolaev, B. (2019). Capital is not enough: Opportunity entrepreneurship and formal institutions. Small Business Economics,53, 709–738. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-018-0068-7ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Boudreaux, C., Nikolaev, B., & Holcombe, R. (2018). Corruption and destructive entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics,51, 181–202. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-017-9927-xArticleGoogle Scholar
- Boudreaux, C., Nikolaev, B. N., & Klein, P. (2019). Socio-cognitive traits and entrepreneurship: The moderating role of economic institutions. Journal of Business Venturing,34, 178–196. ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Boudreaux, C. J., Bennett, D. L., Lucas, D. S., & Nikolaev, B. N. (2022). Taking mental models seriously: Institutions, entrepreneurship, and the mediating role of socio-cognitive traits. Small Business Economics. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-022-00712-8ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Boudreaux, C., Coats, R.M., & Davis, E.H., (2012). The dark side of state competition for foreign direct investment: That which is seen and that which is not seen. Southern Business & Economic Journal, 35(1), 35–52.
- Bucovetsky, S. (2005). Public input competition. Journal of Public Economics,89, 1763–1787. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2004.07.001ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Buffart, M., Croidieu, G., Kim, P. H., & Bowman, R. (2020). Even winners need to learn: How government entrepreneurship programs can support innovative ventures. Research Policy, Innovative start-ups and policy initiatives,49, 104052. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2020.104052ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Bylund, P. L., (2016). The seen, the unseen, and the unrealized: How regulations affect our everyday lives. Lexington Books.
- Coad, A., & Srhoj, S. (2020). Catching gazelles with a lasso: Big data techniques for the prediction of high-growth firms. Small Business Economics,55, 541–565. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-019-00203-3ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Coomes, P. A., Fernandez, J., & Gohmann, S. F. (2013). The rate of proprietorship among metropolitan areas: The impact of the local economic environment and capital resources. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice,37, 745–770. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6520.2012.00511.xArticleGoogle Scholar
- Crozet, M., Mayer, T., & Mucchielli, J.-L. (2004). How do firms agglomerate? A study of FDI in France. Regional Science and Urban Economics,34, 27–54. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0166-0462(03)00010-3ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Cumming, D., & Johan, S. (2010). The differential impact of the internet on spurring regional entrepreneurship. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice,34, 857–884. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6520.2009.00348.xArticleGoogle Scholar
- Cumming, D., Johan, S., & MacIntosh, J. G. (2017). A drop in an empty pond: Canadian public policy towards venture capital. Econ Polit Ind,44, 103–117. https://doi.org/10.1007/s40812-016-0063-4ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Cumming, D., Johan, S., & Zhang, Y. (2018). Public policy towards entrepreneurial finance: Spillovers and the scale-up gap. Oxford Review of Economic Policy,34, 652–675. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxrep/gry012ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Dahl, M. S., & Sorenson, O. (2012). Home sweet home: Entrepreneurs’ location choices and the performance of their ventures. Management Science,58, 1059–1071. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1110.1476ArticleGoogle Scholar
- De Soto, H. (2000). The mystery of capital: Why capitalism triumphs in the west and fails everywhere else. Basic Books
- Devereux, M. P., Griffith, R., & Simpson, H. (2007). Firm location decisions, regional grants and agglomeration externalities. Journal of Public Economics,91, 413–435. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2006.12.002ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Faria, J. R. (2016). Location clusters, FDI and local entrepreneurs: Consistent public policy. Journal of the Knowledge Economy,7, 858–868. https://doi.org/10.1007/s13132-015-0272-5ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Faria, J. R., Prado, M., & Ferreira, J. J. (2021). Informality, infrastructure investments, and new firms’ creation: The location strategy. Journal of the Knowledge Economy. https://doi.org/10.1007/s13132-021-00727-8ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Feldman, M., Francis, J., & Bercovitz, J. (2005). Creating a cluster while building a firm: Entrepreneurs and the formation of industrial clusters. Regional Studies,39, 129–141. https://doi.org/10.1080/0034340052000320888ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Folsom, B. W. (1991). The myth of the robber barons: A new look at the rise of big business in America. USA: Young Americas Foundation
- Fredriksson, A. (2020). One stop shops for public services: Evidence from citizen service centers in Brazil. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management,39, 1133–1165. https://doi.org/10.1002/pam.22255ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Fritsch, M. (2008). How does new business formation affect regional development? Introduction to the special issue. Small Business Economics,30, 1–14. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-007-9057-y
- Galbraith, C. S. (1985). High-technology location and development: The case of Orange County. California Management Review,28, 98–109. https://doi.org/10.2307/41165172ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Glaeser, E. L., Rosenthal, S. S., & Strange, W. C. (2010). Urban economics and entrepreneurship. Journal of Urban Economics, Special Issue: Cities and Entrepreneurship,67, 1–14. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jue.2009.10.005ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Goodman, J.P, Meany, J.W, & Pate, L.E. (1992). The government as entrepreneur: Industrial development and the creation of new ventures. In: Sexton, D.L., & Kasarda, J.D. (Eds.), The State of the Art of Entrepreneurship. Boston: PWS_Kent
- Greenstone, M., & Moretti, E., (2003). Bidding for industrial plants: Does winning a “million dollar plant” increase welfare? (Working Paper No. 9844), Working Paper Series. National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w9844
- Grimes, S. (2000). Rural areas in the information society: Diminishing distance or increasing learning capacity? Journal of Rural Studies,16, 13–21. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0743-0167(99)00027-3ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Gwartney, J., Lawson, R., & Hall, J., (2019). Economic freedom of the world 2019 annual report. The Fraser Institute. https://www.fraserinstitute.org/studies/economic-freedom-of-the-world-2019-annual-report
- Hayter, R. (1997). The dynamics of industrial location: The factory, the firm and the production system. Wiley. Google Scholar
- Henrekson, M., & Stenkula, M. (2010). Entrepreneurship and public policy. In: Acs, Z.J., & Audretsch, D.B. (Eds.) Handbook of Entrepreneurship Research (pp. 595–637). USA: Springer
- Henrekson, M., & Johansson, D. (2010). Gazelles as job creators: A survey and interpretation of the evidence. Small Business Economics,35, 227–244. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-009-9172-zArticleGoogle Scholar
- Henrekson, M., & Sanandaji, T. (2011). The interaction of entrepreneurship and institutions. Journal of Institutional Economics,7, 47–75. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137410000342ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Holcombe, R. G. (1998). Entrepreneurship and economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics,1, 45–62. ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Holtz-Eakin, D. (2000). Public policy toward entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics,15, 283–291. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1011153921409ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Lee, Y. S. (2018). Government guaranteed small business loans and regional growth. Journal of Business Venturing,33, 70–83. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusvent.2017.11.001ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Lerner, J. (2010). The future of public efforts to boost entrepreneurship and venture capital. Small Business Economics,35, 255–264. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-010-9298-zArticleGoogle Scholar
- Lucas, D. S., & Boudreaux, C. (2020). National regulation, state-level policy, and local job creation in the United States: A multilevel perspective. Research Policy,49, 103952. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2020.103952ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Luo, L., Ma, X., Makino, S., & Shinkle, G. A. (2020). Cluster status and new venture creation. Journal of Business Venturing,35, 105985. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusvent.2019.105985ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Mason, C., & Brown, R. (2013). Creating good public policy to support high-growth firms. Small Business Economics,40, 211–225. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-011-9369-9ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Mazzucato, M. (2018). Mission-oriented innovation policies: Challenges and opportunities. Industrial and Corporate Change,27, 803–815. https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/dty034ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Mazzucato, M. (2015). Entrepreneurial state: Debunking public vs. private sector myths. USA: Anthem Press
- Mendicino, C., & Prado, M. (2014). Heterogeneous firms and the impact of government policy on welfare and informality. Economics Letters,124, 151–156. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2014.04.018ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Michael, S. C., & Pearce, J. A. (2009). The need for innovation as a rationale for government involvement in entrepreneurship. Entrepreneurship & Regional Development,21, 285–302. https://doi.org/10.1080/08985620802279999ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Minniti, M. (2008). The role of government policy on entrepreneurial activity: Productive, unproductive, or destructive? Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice,32, 779–790. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6520.2008.00255.xArticleGoogle Scholar
- Morgan, H. M., Sui, S., & Baum, M. (2018). Are SMEs with immigrant owners exceptional exporters? Journal of Business Venturing,33, 241–260. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusvent.2017.12.003ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Murphy, K. M., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1991). The allocation of talent: Implications for growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics,106, 503–530. https://doi.org/10.2307/2937945ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Nikolaev, B., Boudreaux, C., & Palich, L. E. (2018). Cross-country determinants of early stage necessity and opportunity-motivated entrepreneurship: Accounting for model uncertainty. Journal of Small Business Management. https://doi.org/10.1111/jsbm.12400ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Obaji, N. O., & Olugu, M. U. (2014). The role of government policy in entrepreneurship development. Science Journal of Business and Management,2, 109–115. ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Ogura, L. (2018). Informality and exogenous regulations in regional economies. Economics Bulletin,38, 892–900. Google Scholar
- Ouwersloot, H., & Rietveld, P. (2000). The geography of R&D: Tobit analysis and a Bayesian approach to mapping R&D activities in the Netherlands. Environment and Planning A,32, 1673–1688. https://doi.org/10.1068/a3336ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Packard, M. D., & Bylund, P. L. (2018). On the relationship between inequality and entrepreneurship. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal,12, 3–22. https://doi.org/10.1002/sej.1270ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Padilla-Pérez, R., & Gaudin, Y. (2014). Science, technology and innovation policies in small and developing economies: The case of Central America. Research Policy,43, 749–759. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2013.10.011ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Parker, S. C. (2018). The economics of entrepreneurship. Cambridge University Press. BookGoogle Scholar
- Parker, S. C. (2020). Editorial: On submitting economics articles to JBV. Journal of Business Venturing,35, 106018. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusvent.2020.106018ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Popper, K. R. (1934). Logik der Forschung. Springer, Hutchinson & Co.
- Prado, M. (2011). Government policy in the formal and informal sectors. European Economic Review,55, 1120–1136. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2011.04.010ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Sabat, W., & Pilewicz, T. (2019). Business location decision: The behavioural aspect in empirical research. Journal of Management and Financial Sciences, 99–109. https://doi.org/10.33119/JMFS.2019.37.6
- Say, J. B. (1828). Cours complet d’économie politique pratique. Paris: Chez Rapilly, Libraire
- Schumpeter, J. A. (1934). The theory of economic development: An inquiry into profits, capital, credit, interest, and the business cycle. Transaction Publishers
- Shane, S. (2009). Why encouraging more people to become entrepreneurs is bad public policy. Small Business Economics,33, 141–149. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-009-9215-5ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Slattery, C. (2018). Bidding for firms: Subsidy competition in the US. SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3250356.
- Sorenson, O. (2018). Social networks and the geography of entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics,51, 527–537. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-018-0076-7ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Taylor, L. (1992). Infrastructural competition among jurisdictions. Journal of Public Economics,49, 241–259. https://doi.org/10.1016/0047-2727(92)90022-8ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Thurik, R., & Wennekers, S. (2004). Entrepreneurship, small business and economic growth. Journal of Small Business and Enterprise Development,11, 140–149. https://doi.org/10.1108/14626000410519173ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Urbano, D., Aparicio, S., & Audretsch, D. (2019). Twenty-five years of research on institutions, entrepreneurship, and economic growth: What has been learned? Small Business Economics,53, 21–49. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-018-0038-0ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Van De Ven, H. (1993). The development of an infrastructure for entrepreneurship. Journal of Business Venturing, Special Theoretical Issue,8, 211–230. https://doi.org/10.1016/0883-9026(93)90028-4ArticleGoogle Scholar
- van Praag, C. M., & Versloot, P. H. (2007). What is the value of entrepreneurship? A review of recent research. Small Business Economics,29, 351–382. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-007-9074-xArticleGoogle Scholar
- Welter, F., Baker, T., Audretsch, D. B., & Gartner, W. B. (2017). Everyday entrepreneurship—A call for entrepreneurship research to embrace entrepreneurial diversity. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice,41, 311–321. https://doi.org/10.1111/etap.12258ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Wennberg, K., & Sandström, C. (Eds.) (2022). Questioning the entrepreneurial state: Status-quo, pitfalls, and the need for credible innovation policy. Springer Nature. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-94273-1
- Wennekers, S., & Thurik, R. (1999). Linking entrepreneurship and economic growth. Small Business Economics,13, 27–56. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1008063200484ArticleGoogle Scholar
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
- Department of Economics, Florida Atlantic University, Boca Raton, FL, USA João Ricardo Faria & Christopher J. Boudreaux
- Department of Economics, Grand Valley State University, Allendale, MI, USA Laudo Ogura
- Department of Economics, Copenhagen Business School, Frederiksberg, Denmark Mauricio Prado
- João Ricardo Faria